The Misadvetures of the Eurozone
Sottotitolo:
The ultra-liberal principles that govern the eurozone exclude direct public intervention. The result is a decade characterized by lower growth and higher unemployment in the developed world. What strikes us most about the coronavirus pandemic is that we know the consequences, in many too many irreparable cases, of the disease, but we do not know the remedy. Medical science needs time (to discover a solution). In the autumn we will have to take cover by taking the measures we have learned in the toughest months. In other words, coronavirus imposes a more or less long phase of uncertainty. We cannot say as much about its economic long term consequences, but some of theirs have already been experienced. Indeed, devastating social consequences, the main manifestation of which is the closure of productive and commercial activities that have created a new army of unemployed people. For the time being, more or less all the most affected countries have tried to shelter it by expanding the unemployment benefit and all possible forms of assistance. The OIT predicts an increase in global unemployment of many hundred million people. The European Commission expects unemployment to rise sharply in the eurozone. In the Bank of Italy's annual report at the end of May, Governor Ignazio Visco spoke bluntly about the reasons for the alarm. The collapse of the economy could be, in Italy, between 9 and 13 percent. It's a post-war situation, we've been reminded. But we can also add an aggravation: the fall today is sudden and vertical, and its impact so fast that it does not leave an effective and prompt remedy. We know, in other words, the diagnosis, but not the therapy. We also know the chain of events: unemployment causes a fall in the purchasing power and in the demand and consequently in the output (or production). Businesses do not invest and many are calling for a disappear increasing unemployment in a vicious circle. That is an extremely insidious process of deflation that does not allow for simple (easy) exit (way out). At the heart of the problem is the fall in investment that follows the fall in demand. It is a typical side of a traditional crisis. The difference is that the current one is rightly deemed the most serious in the post-war time in a self-driving spiral. Governments are trying to resort to extraordinary and unreadable remedies. In the US, Trump had begun proposing a public intervention in the order of one billion dollars. Virtually nothing. Democrats imposed more than double the amount, and then Democrats in the House of Representatives passed a three-trillion-dollar intervention, which is now blocked in the Senate under the Republican filibustering (or obstructionism). In Japan we can see the most decisive and striking example of intervention. Initially, the government had decided to increase public spending by one billion dollars. Subsequently the government intervened again, foreseeing a commitment of one trillion seven hundred billion dollars. The comparison with the European Union is instructive and depressing. The Franco-German proposal of 500 billion grants to help the European Union’s recovery has been increased to 750 billion with an addition of loans proposed by the European Commission. For comparison, it is worth remembering that the population of the EU is almost four times that of Japan and the European commitment less than half. However, the bleakest aspect is that the allocation of resources to the countries most affected by the pandemic– firstly, Italy and Spain - will be available (provided that the consent of the 27 EU countries is found), in 2021. The absurdity is blatant. It's like discovering a general bout of typhus today and distributing the most suitable antibiotic in a far future, after the disease has spread with devastating effects.
We are seeing remedies in other countries. In the face of them, those proposed by the EU authorities are bleak if not grotesque. After the Great Depression of the early 1930s, crises combining falling production and mass unemployment in a chained fall of supply and demand, the solution was definitively identified in public intervention. The state is the only entity that can reactivate production in a big way by focusing mainly on infrastructure works of different sizes, but all able to generate employment in an intertwined and circular sequence of investment-employment-wages-consumption-production. The picture changes profile if we look instead at Germany, which has planned over a thousand billion as a guarantee for loans and in support of the economy. Then the government made an unusual choice for Germany consisting of a direct commitment of 130 billion from the budget to support household income and public investment. Significant, among others, the choice to reduce the different VAT rates, lowering the highest from 19 to 16 percent for the second half of the current year - for a comparison, in Italy it is currently equal to 22 percent. Other measures concern household income, such as a 300 euro allowance for each child. Social Democrat Olaf Scholz, deputy chancellor and finance minister, stressed that this is the largest public intervention since post-war times. But it is not only a matter of time, although decisive. Looking, for example, to Italy, the use of resources in the form of grants and, mainly, loans of around 180 billion (but according to the calculations of the Cottarelli institute, around 150 billion) is conditioned by the objectives set by Brussels. That is to say that the funds must be allocated, under the control of the Commission over the course of four years, to two specific sectors: the environment and new technologies. Nothing that already, not just next year, concerns (affects) the devastating economic and social effects of the pandemic. By which what effects? (With what effects?) According to ECB calculations, the crisis entails an average fall in national income in the eurozone of over 8 percent - a fall that in Italy, according to the forecasts of the governor of the Bank of Italy, Visco, can extend up to 13 percent of the GDP during 2020. With the consequence, according to the European Commission, of an unemployment increase of over one million employees. Incidentally, this will end leading to a higher unemployment in the most fragile regions of the South of Italy than that experienced in Greece in the worst moments of the crisis after 2010. It is in this unprecedented scenario that the European institutions propose financial aid with the limits we have seen, over the next year, when the crisis resulting from the pandemic has already produced disastrous effects, in many ways irreparable, on millions of families. But the ruling class and the big press at its service seem not to notice it or, presumably, preferring not to notice it, reserving their approval for European technocracy. 3. Probably aware of the ineffectiveness of the European Commission's intervention, we have seen the ECB's decision to add 600 billion to the 750 already available for interventions tackling the current economic crisis. Christine Lagarde was proud of a decision that bypasses the warnings of the German Constitutional Court tending to curtail (restrict) the ECB's activity, calling into question its independence. But in the present case, the ECB's decision does not violate the rules invoked by the German Constitution Court, since any funds are earmarked for the private banking sector and not as aid destined to the Member States. Jens Weidmann, president of the Bundesbank, a rigorously vigilant mastiff vis-à-vis the ECB in Draghi's time, not only fully justified the central bank's decision, but also, surprisingly, declared himself in favor of a greater financial commitment. A practice in which there has been nothing new for almost a century after the economic and social catastrophe of the Great Depression of the early Thirties. There is also no need to retrace very distant experiences. It is enough to go back to the experience of the 2008-09 crisis in America, faced, according to many authoritative critics, with insufficient tools but, nevertheless, capable of initiating a ten-year recovery of the economy, the longest in the US history, marked by the lowest unemployment rate in the past half century. 4. Public investments in an extraordinary quantity of fields, both direct and as a stimulus for private ones, are part of a common experience: from bad bridges and roads, to the outskirts of big cities, to water systems (the major intervention Roosevelt's New Deal was the TVA, the regulation of the water course in Tennessee Valley). Not to mention the support for all public works, even minor ones, which can involve the activities of small and medium-sized enterprises, which represent the greatest source of employment. Nothing new compared to the past experiences in all the countries facing a serious crisis. But the ultra-liberal principles that govern the eurozone, based on the exclusive role of markets and free competition, categorically exclude direct public investment. Antonio Lettieri
Antonio Lettieri is Editor of Insight and President of CISS – Center for International Social Studies (Roma). He was National Secretary of CGIL; Member of ILO Governing Body,and Advisor of Labor Minister for European Affairs.(a.lettieri@insightweb.it) Insight - Free thinking for global social progress
Free thinking for global social progress |